Condorcet method (English Wikipedia)

Analysis of information sources in references of the Wikipedia article "Condorcet method" in English language version.

refsWebsite
Global rank English rank
2nd place
2nd place
11th place
8th place
1st place
1st place
5th place
5th place
26th place
20th place
69th place
59th place
3rd place
3rd place
6th place
6th place
179th place
183rd place
low place
low place
274th place
309th place
low place
low place
9,325th place
9,314th place
120th place
125th place
102nd place
76th place
741st place
577th place
low place
low place
1,031st place
879th place
1,564th place
1,028th place
2,685th place
1,516th place
low place
low place
low place
low place
low place
low place
1,734th place
1,312th place
613th place
456th place
low place
5,968th place
low place
low place
low place
low place
low place
low place
low place
low place

archive.org

  • Nanson, E. J. (1882). "Methods of election". Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria. 19: 207–208. although Ware's method cannot return the worst, it may return the next worst.
  • Nanson, E. J. (1882). "Methods of election". Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria. 19: 217.

archives-ouvertes.fr

halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr

arxiv.org

  • Darlington, Richard B. (2018). "Are Condorcet and minimax voting systems the best?". arXiv:1807.01366 [physics.soc-ph]. CC [Condorcet] systems typically allow tied ranks. If a voter fails to rank a candidate, they are typically presumed to rank them below anyone whom they did rank explicitly.
  • Schulze, Markus (2018). "The Schulze Method of Voting". p. 351. arXiv:1804.02973 [cs.GT]. The Condorcet criterion for single-winner elections (section 4.7) is important because, when there is a Condorcet winner b ∈ A, then it is still a Condorcet winner when alternatives a1,...,an ∈ A \ {b} are removed. So an alternative b ∈ A doesn't owe his property of being a Condorcet winner to the presence of some other alternatives. Therefore, when we declare a Condorcet winner b ∈ A elected whenever a Condorcet winner exists, we know that no other alternatives a1,...,an ∈ A \ {b} have changed the result of the election without being elected.

books.google.com

cmu.edu

cs.cmu.edu

core.ac.uk

  • Truchon, Michel (October 1998). "AN EXTENSION OF THE CONDORCET CRITERION AND KEMENY ORDERS" (PDF). A first objective of this paper is to propose a formalization of this idea, called the Extended Condorcet Criterion (XCC). In essence, it says that if the set of alternatives can be partitioned in such a way that all members of a subset of this partition defeat all alternatives belonging to subsets with a higher index, then the former should obtain a better rank than the latter.

doi.org

doi.org

  • Gehrlein, William V.; Valognes, Fabrice (2001). "Condorcet efficiency: A preference for indifference". Social Choice and Welfare. 18: 193–205. doi:10.1007/s003550000071. S2CID 10493112. The Condorcet winner in an election is the candidate who would be able to defeat all other candidates in a series of pairwise elections.
  • Tideman, T. Nicolaus; Plassmann, Florenz (2011). "Modeling the Outcomes of Vote-Casting in Actual Elections". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1627787. ISSN 1556-5068. A common definition of a voting cycle is the absence of a strict pairwise majority rule winner (SPMRW) … if no candidate beats all other candidates in pairwise comparisons.
  • Wallis, W. D. (2014). "Simple Elections II: Condorcet's Method". The Mathematics of Elections and Voting. Springer. pp. 19–32. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-09810-4_3. ISBN 978-3-319-09809-8.
  • Gehrlein, William V.; Fishburn, Peter C. (1976). "Condorcet's Paradox and Anonymous Preference Profiles". Public Choice. 26: 1–18. doi:10.1007/BF01725789. JSTOR 30022874?seq=1. S2CID 153482816. Condorcet's paradox [6] of simple majority voting occurs in a voting situation [...] if for every alternative there is a second alternative which more voters prefer to the first alternative than conversely.
  • Colomer, Josep (2013). "Ramon Llull: From Ars Electionis to Social Choice Theory". Social Choice and Welfare. 40 (2): 317–328. doi:10.1007/s00355-011-0598-2. hdl:10261/125715. S2CID 43015882.
  • McLean, Iain; Urken, Arnold B. (1992). "Did Jefferson or Madison understand Condorcet's theory of social choice?". Public Choice. 73 (4): 445–457. doi:10.1007/BF01789561. S2CID 145167169. Binary procedures of the Jefferson/Robert variety will select the Condorcet winner if one exists
  • Igersheim, Herrade; Durand, François; Hamlin, Aaron; Laslier, Jean-François (January 2022). "Comparing voting methods: 2016 US presidential election". European Journal of Political Economy. 71: 102057. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2021.102057.
  • Nurmi, Hannu (2012), "On the Relevance of Theoretical Results to Voting System Choice", in Felsenthal, Dan S.; Machover, Moshé (eds.), Electoral Systems, Studies in Choice and Welfare, Springer Berlin Heidelberg, pp. 255–274, doi:10.1007/978-3-642-20441-8_10, ISBN 9783642204401, S2CID 12562825
  • Young, H. P. (1988). "Condorcet's Theory of Voting" (PDF). American Political Science Review. 82 (4): 1231–1244. doi:10.2307/1961757. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 1961757. S2CID 14908863. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2018-12-22.
  • Felsenthal, Dan S.; Tideman, Nicolaus (2014). "Weak Condorcet winner(s) revisited". Public Choice. 160 (3–4): 313–326. doi:10.1007/s11127-014-0180-4. S2CID 154447142. A weak Condorcet winner (WCW) is an alternative, y, that no majority of voters rank below any other alternative, z, but is not a SCW [Condorcet winner].

dx.doi.org

electowiki.org

elekto.dev

equal.vote

  • "Condorcet". Equal Vote Coalition. Retrieved 2021-04-25.

freefaculty.org

pj.freefaculty.org

  • Johnson, Paul E. (May 27, 2005). "Voting Systems" (PDF). Formally, the Smith set is defined as the smaller of two sets:
    1. The set of all alternatives, X.
    2. A subset A ⊂ X such that each member of A can defeat every member of X that is not in A, which we call B=X − A.

handle.net

hdl.handle.net

jstor.org

liquidfeedback.org

principles.liquidfeedback.org

lpwa.org

mcdougall.org.uk

natlib.govt.nz

rsnz.natlib.govt.nz

ox.ac.uk

nuff.ox.ac.uk

princeton.edu

researchgate.net

semanticscholar.org

api.semanticscholar.org

  • Gehrlein, William V.; Valognes, Fabrice (2001). "Condorcet efficiency: A preference for indifference". Social Choice and Welfare. 18: 193–205. doi:10.1007/s003550000071. S2CID 10493112. The Condorcet winner in an election is the candidate who would be able to defeat all other candidates in a series of pairwise elections.
  • Green-Armytage, James (2011). "Four Condorcet-Hare Hybrid Methods for Single-Winner Elections" (PDF). S2CID 15220771. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2013-06-03.
  • Gehrlein, William V.; Fishburn, Peter C. (1976). "Condorcet's Paradox and Anonymous Preference Profiles". Public Choice. 26: 1–18. doi:10.1007/BF01725789. JSTOR 30022874?seq=1. S2CID 153482816. Condorcet's paradox [6] of simple majority voting occurs in a voting situation [...] if for every alternative there is a second alternative which more voters prefer to the first alternative than conversely.
  • Colomer, Josep (2013). "Ramon Llull: From Ars Electionis to Social Choice Theory". Social Choice and Welfare. 40 (2): 317–328. doi:10.1007/s00355-011-0598-2. hdl:10261/125715. S2CID 43015882.
  • McLean, Iain; Urken, Arnold B. (1992). "Did Jefferson or Madison understand Condorcet's theory of social choice?". Public Choice. 73 (4): 445–457. doi:10.1007/BF01789561. S2CID 145167169. Binary procedures of the Jefferson/Robert variety will select the Condorcet winner if one exists
  • Wang, Tiance; Cuff, P.; Kulkarni, Sanjeev (2013). "Condorcet Methods are Less Susceptible to Strategic Voting" (PDF). S2CID 8230466. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2021-11-02.
  • Nurmi, Hannu (2012), "On the Relevance of Theoretical Results to Voting System Choice", in Felsenthal, Dan S.; Machover, Moshé (eds.), Electoral Systems, Studies in Choice and Welfare, Springer Berlin Heidelberg, pp. 255–274, doi:10.1007/978-3-642-20441-8_10, ISBN 9783642204401, S2CID 12562825
  • Young, H. P. (1988). "Condorcet's Theory of Voting" (PDF). American Political Science Review. 82 (4): 1231–1244. doi:10.2307/1961757. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 1961757. S2CID 14908863. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2018-12-22.
  • Felsenthal, Dan S.; Tideman, Nicolaus (2014). "Weak Condorcet winner(s) revisited". Public Choice. 160 (3–4): 313–326. doi:10.1007/s11127-014-0180-4. S2CID 154447142. A weak Condorcet winner (WCW) is an alternative, y, that no majority of voters rank below any other alternative, z, but is not a SCW [Condorcet winner].
  • Green-Armytage, James. "Why majoritarian election methods should be Condorcet-efficient". Economics. S2CID 18348996.

springer.com

link.springer.com

stanford.edu

plato.stanford.edu

  • Pacuit, Eric (2019), "Voting Methods", in Zalta, Edward N. (ed.), The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Fall 2019 ed.), Metaphysics Research Lab, Stanford University, retrieved 2020-10-16

economics.stanford.edu

  • Thesis [permanent dead link] "IRV satisfies the later-no-harm criterion and the Condorcet loser criterion but fails monotonicity, independence of irrelevant alternatives, and the Condorcet criterion."

uni-augsburg.de

math.uni-augsburg.de

usenet.org.uk

  • "Guidelines for Group Creation for uk.*". www.usenet.org.uk. Retrieved 2024-12-13. For a vote between several mutually exclusive options, the votetaking organisation will establish, for each possible pair of options A and B, how many voters prefer A over B and vice versa. … The method of determining the result when there are several mutually exclusive options, as described in paragraph 4 of The Result, is essentially that devised by the French mathematician the Marquis de Condorcet (1743-94).

vermont.gov

legislature.vermont.gov

votingmatters.org.uk

web.archive.org

wikimedia.org

meta.wikimedia.org

worldcat.org

search.worldcat.org