Labor theory of value (English Wikipedia)

Analysis of information sources in references of the Wikipedia article "Labor theory of value" in English language version.

refsWebsite
Global rank English rank
1st place
1st place
803rd place
826th place
2nd place
2nd place
6,572nd place
4,351st place
low place
low place
3,576th place
2,563rd place
3rd place
3rd place
low place
low place
11th place
8th place
18th place
17th place
4th place
4th place
179th place
183rd place
8,043rd place
6,448th place
5th place
5th place
4,270th place
2,990th place
1,735th place
3,129th place
low place
low place
1,041st place
733rd place
26th place
20th place
1,601st place
1,117th place
low place
low place
259th place
188th place
3,237th place
2,989th place
low place
low place
low place
low place
6,232nd place
6,504th place
low place
low place
149th place
178th place
low place
low place
9,448th place
8,131st place
102nd place
76th place
low place
low place
4,710th place
3,766th place
low place
low place

blackened.net

flag.blackened.net

books.google.com

  • Rubin, Isaak Ilyich (2020). Essays on Marx's Theory of Value. Pattern Books. ISBN 978-3-0340-0472-5. ...even though the quantity of socially-necessary labor required for the production of one pair of shoes did not change, because of the excessive supply the shoes are sold according to a market price which is below the market-value determined by the socially-necessary labor. The interpreters of Marx ...establish... an 'economic' concept of necessary labor i.e., recognizing that socially-necessary labor changes not only in relation to changes in the productive power of labor but also in relation to changes in the balance between social supply and demand.
  • Anson Rabinbach, "The human motor: Energy, fatigue, and the origins of modernity"

doi.org

econstor.eu

eh.net

ehu.eus

gumilla.org

handle.net

hdl.handle.net

harvard.edu

ui.adsabs.harvard.edu

inclusivedemocracy.org

  • Fotopoulos, Takis. "Beyond Marx and Proudhon". Thus, the classical solution of expressing the value of goods and services in terms of man hours, which was developed by the orthodox (political) economists of the time, was adopted by both Proudhon and Marx.

informit.com.au

search.informit.com.au

infoshop.org

  • "The most basic difference is that the individualist anarchists rooted their ideas in the labour theory of value while the "anarcho"-capitalists favour mainstream marginalist theory." An Anarchist FAQ Archived 2013-03-15 at the Wayback Machine
  • "Like Proudhon, they desired a (libertarian) socialist system based on the market but without exploitation and which rested on possession rather than capitalist private property."An Anarchist FAQ Archived 2013-03-15 at the Wayback Machine
  • Darby Tillis. "An Anarchist FAQ". Infoshop.org. Archived from the original on November 23, 2010. Retrieved September 20, 2010.

jstor.org

keenomics.s3.amazonaws.com

libertarian-labyrinth.org

  • William Bailie, "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on February 4, 2012. Retrieved June 17, 2013.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link) Josiah Warren: The First American Anarchist – A Sociological Study, Boston: Small, Maynard & Co., 1906, p. 20

libertyfund.org

oll.libertyfund.org

marxists.org

  • Unless otherwise noted, the description of the labor process and the role of the value of means of production in this section are drawn from chapter 7 of Capital vol1 (Marx 1867). Marx, Karl (1867), Engels, Friedrich (ed.), Capital, vol. 1, Samuel Moore and Edward Aveling, ISBN 978-0-394-72657-1, retrieved July 5, 2006 – via Marxists Internet Archive ([Internet edition: 1999] [1887 English edition]).
  • "Chris Harman: How Marxism Works (5. The labour theory of value)". www.marxists.org. Retrieved February 4, 2024. Everything people have used historically to create wealth – whether a Neolithic stone axe or a modern computer – once had to be made by human labour. Even if the axe was shaped with tools, the tools in turn were the product of previous labour. That is why Karl Marx used to refer to the means of production as 'dead labour'. When businessmen boast of the capital they possess, in reality they are boasting that they have gained control of a vast pool of the labour of previous generations – and that does not mean the labour of their ancestors, who laboured no more than they do now.
  • "Wealth of Nations — Bk 1 Chpt 05". www.marxists.org. Retrieved February 4, 2024. The real price of every thing, what every thing really costs to the man who wants to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring it. What every thing is really worth to the man who has acquired it, and who wants to dispose of it or exchange it for something else, is the toil and trouble which it can save to himself, and which it can impose upon other people.
  • Marx, Karl. "Economic Manuscripts: Value, Price and Profit". www.marxists.org. Retrieved January 28, 2024. You would be altogether mistaken in fancying that the value of labour or any other commodity whatever is ultimately fixed by supply and demand. Supply and demand regulate nothing but the temporary fluctuations of market prices. They will explain to you why the market price of a commodity rises above or sinks below its value, but they can never account for the value itself. Suppose supply and demand to equilibrate, or, as the economists call it, to cover each other. Why, the very moment these opposite forces become equal they paralyze each other, and cease to work in the one or other direction. At the moment when supply and demand equilibrate each other, and therefore cease to act, the market price of a commodity coincides with its real value, with the standard price round which its market prices oscillate. In inquiring into the nature of that VALUE, we have therefore nothing at all to do with the temporary effects on market prices of supply and demand. The same holds true of wages and of the prices of all other commodities.
  • "Ernest Mandel: The Labor Theory of Value and "Monopoly Capitalism" (1967)". www.marxists.org. Retrieved January 29, 2024. The labor theory of value implies that, in terms of value, the total mass of surplus value to be distributed every year is a given quantity. It depends on the value of variable capital and on the rate of surplus value. Price competition cannot change that given quantity (except when it influences the division of the newly created income between workers and capitalists, i.e. depresses or increases real wages, and thereby increases or depresses the rate of surplus value)...It means that the distribution of the given quantity of surplus value is changed, in favor of the monopolists and at the expense of the non-monopolized sectors....Under monopoly capitalism as under "competitive capitalism" the two basic forces explaining capital accumulation remain competition between capitalists (for appropriating bigger shares of surplus value) and competition between capitalists and workers (for increasing the rate of surplus value)."
  • Marx 1867. Marx, Karl (1867), Engels, Friedrich (ed.), Capital, vol. 1, Samuel Moore and Edward Aveling, ISBN 978-0-394-72657-1, retrieved July 5, 2006 – via Marxists Internet Archive ([Internet edition: 1999] [1887 English edition]).
  • Marx, Karl (1865). "Value and Labour". Value, Price and Profit – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  • Ricardo, David (1817). "On The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation". www.marxists.org. Retrieved August 19, 2020.
  • Marx, Karl (1875). "1". Critique of the Gotha Program – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  • D'Arcy, Jim, "Socialist Economics 4: Do Machines Produce Surplus Value?", Socialist Standard, 1974

mcmaster.ca

socserv2.socsci.mcmaster.ca

mises.org

mutualist.org

nih.gov

ncbi.nlm.nih.gov

  • Confer: Weizsäcker, Carl Christian von (2010): A New Technical Progress Function (1962). German Economic Review 11/3 (first publication of an article written in 1962); Weizsäcker Carl Christian von, and Paul A. Samuelson (1971): A new labor theory of value for rational planning through use of the bourgeois profit rate. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences (facsimile).

qmul.ac.uk

qmro.qmul.ac.uk

repec.org

econpapers.repec.org

  • Taylor, Kit Sims (2001). Human Society and the Global Economy (Report). SUNY-Oswego, Department of Economics. Value lies at the core of the economic adjustment process. If the actual price of something were above the value, the extra profits to be made would attract more firms into that industry leading to a greater supply and – eventually – lower prices; conversely, if the actual price of something were below the value, the losses – or sub-normal profits – would drive firms out of that industry leading to a smaller supply and – eventually – higher prices.

sciencedirect.com

semanticscholar.org

api.semanticscholar.org

slate.com

spartacus-educational.com

stanford.edu

plato.stanford.edu

  • Hansson, Sven Ove; Grüne-Yanoff, Till (November 14, 2017). Zalta, Edward N. (ed.). "Preferences". The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer 2018 Edition). Retrieved November 21, 2020.

utoronto.ca

individual.utoronto.ca

virginia.edu

xroads.virginia.edu

web.archive.org

wix.com

australianpe.wix.com

  • cf E F Schumacher,Small Is Beautiful, Pt 1, ch 1. Mike Beggs, "Zombie Marx and Modern Economics, or How I Learned to Stop Worrying and Forget the Transformation Problem." Journal of Australian Political Economy, issue 70, Summer 2012/13, p. 16 [1]; Gary Mongiovi, "Vulgar economy in Marxian garb: a critique of Temporal Single System Marxism." In: Review of Radical Political Economics, Vol. 34, Issue 4, December 2002, pp. 393–416 [398].

worldcat.org

search.worldcat.org

  • Hunt, E. K.; Lautzenheiser, Mark (2011). History of economic thought l: a critical perspective (3rd ed.). Armonk, New York: M. E. Sharpe. ISBN 978-1-317-46859-2. OCLC 903283190.

yorku.ca

bnarchives.yorku.ca