Social ownership (English Wikipedia)

Analysis of information sources in references of the Wikipedia article "Social ownership" in English language version.

refsWebsite
Global rank English rank
6th place
6th place
1st place
1st place
2nd place
2nd place
3rd place
3rd place
485th place
440th place
657th place
613th place
low place
low place
low place
low place
9,546th place
7,865th place
low place
7,394th place
low place
low place
149th place
178th place
5th place
5th place
low place
6,687th place
179th place
183rd place
11th place
8th place
low place
low place
321st place
724th place
7th place
7th place

archive.org

  • Lamont, Corliss (1939). You might like socialism; a way of life for modern man. Modern Age Books, Inc. pp. 239–40. ISBN 978-1-330-53101-3. Under socialism, with its economic security and progressively shorter hours of work, the leisure class is everyone. This new leisure class is not just a passive recipient and consumer of culture; it actively participates and creates, putting into effect the principle enunciated by the late American painter, Robert Hallowell, that 'Each bears a gift for all
  • Hastings, Mason and Pyper, Adrian, Alistair and Hugh (2000). The Oxford Companion to Christian Thought. Oxford University Press. p. 677. ISBN 978-0-19-860024-4. Socialists have always recognized that there are many possible forms of social ownership of which co-operative ownership is one. Nationalization in itself has nothing particularly to do with socialism and has existed under non-socialist and anti-socialist regimes. Kautsky in 1891 pointed out that a 'co-operative commonwealth' could not be the result of the 'general nationalization of all industries' unless there was a change in 'the character of the state'.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  • Wolff and Resnick, Richard and Stephen (1987). Economics: Marxian versus Neoclassical. The Johns Hopkins University Press. pp. 226–27. ISBN 978-0-8018-3480-6. For Marxian theory, socialism and communism represent societies built around a different, noncapitalist form of the fundamental class process. That is a very different thing from a society in which the state appropriates surplus value from the productive laborers it hires and exploits ... These characteristics imply that any person who participates in the communist fundamental class is both a performer and appropriator of surplus labor ... the decision of a state to operate capitalist industrial enterprises has no necessary relation to socialism...
  • Yunker, James (1992). Socialism Revised and Modernized: The Case for Pragmatic Market Socialism. Praeger. pp. 29–31. ISBN 978-0-275-94134-5.
  • Benkler, Yochai (2006). The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom. New Haven, Yale University Press. ISBN 0-300-11056-1.

berniesanders.com

books.google.com

  • Horvat, Branko (2000). "Social ownership". In Michie, Jonathan (ed.). Reader's Guide to the Social Sciences, Volume 1. London and New York: Routledge. pp. 1515–1516. ISBN 9781135932268. Retrieved 15 October 2021. Just as private ownership defines capitalism, social ownership defines socialism. The essential characteristic of socialism in theory is that it destroys social hierarchies, and therefore leads to a politically and economically egalitarian society. Two closely related consequences follow. First, every individual is entitled to an equal ownership share that earns an aliquot part of the total social dividend…Second, in order to eliminate social hierarchy in the workplace, enterprises are run by those employed, and not by the representatives of private or state capital. Thus, the well-known historical tendency of the divorce between ownership and management is brought to an end. The society—i.e. every individual equally—owns capital and those who work are entitled to manage their own economic affairs.

chaloupek.eu

  • Otto Neurath's concepts of socialization and economic calculation and his socialist critics. Retrieved July 5, 2010: "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 12 September 2011. Retrieved 5 July 2010.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)

doi.org

free.fr

gesd.free.fr

geo.coop

jacobin.com

monthlyreview.org

nytimes.com

economix.blogs.nytimes.com

oup.com

academic.oup.com

reference.com

dictionary.reference.com

sciencedirect.com

semanticscholar.org

api.semanticscholar.org

stanford.edu

plato.stanford.edu

theanarchistlibrary.org

web.archive.org

  • Otto Neurath's concepts of socialization and economic calculation and his socialist critics. Retrieved July 5, 2010: "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 12 September 2011. Retrieved 5 July 2010.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  • Bertrand Russell (1932). "In Praise of Idleness". Zpub. Archived from the original on 22 August 2019. Retrieved 16 November 2015. I do not regard Socialism as a gospel of proletarian revenge, nor even, primarily, as a means of securing economic justice. I regard it primarily as an adjustment to machine production demanded by considerations of common sense, and calculated to increase happiness, not only of proletarians, but of all except a tiny minority of the human race.

worldcat.org

search.worldcat.org

zpub.com

  • Bertrand Russell (1932). "In Praise of Idleness". Zpub. Archived from the original on 22 August 2019. Retrieved 16 November 2015. I do not regard Socialism as a gospel of proletarian revenge, nor even, primarily, as a means of securing economic justice. I regard it primarily as an adjustment to machine production demanded by considerations of common sense, and calculated to increase happiness, not only of proletarians, but of all except a tiny minority of the human race.