Solow–Swan model (English Wikipedia)

Analysis of information sources in references of the Wikipedia article "Solow–Swan model" in English language version.

refsWebsite
Global rank English rank
2nd place
2nd place
26th place
20th place
11th place
8th place
102nd place
76th place
5th place
5th place
6th place
6th place
6,325th place
8,806th place
207th place
136th place
3rd place
3rd place
6,348th place
9,940th place
low place
low place
2,318th place
1,652nd place
3,436th place
2,114th place
14th place
14th place
2,388th place
low place
2,969th place
1,994th place
low place
low place

archive.org

archive.today

books.google.com

  • The idea of using a Cobb–Douglas production function at the core of a growth model dates back to Tinbergen, J. (1942). "Zur Theorie der langfristigen Wirtschaftsentwicklung". Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv. 55: 511–549. JSTOR 40430851. See Brems, Hans (1986). "Neoclassical Growth: Tinbergen and Solow". Pioneering Economic Theory, 1630–1980. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. pp. 362–368. ISBN 978-0-8018-2667-2.

doi.org

eafit.edu.co

repository.eafit.edu.co

ens.fr

piketty.pse.ens.fr

fgv.br

bibliotecadigital.fgv.br

georgetown.edu

faculty.georgetown.edu

handle.net

hdl.handle.net

itam.mx

gente.itam.mx

jstor.org

  • The idea of using a Cobb–Douglas production function at the core of a growth model dates back to Tinbergen, J. (1942). "Zur Theorie der langfristigen Wirtschaftsentwicklung". Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv. 55: 511–549. JSTOR 40430851. See Brems, Hans (1986). "Neoclassical Growth: Tinbergen and Solow". Pioneering Economic Theory, 1630–1980. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. pp. 362–368. ISBN 978-0-8018-2667-2.
  • Solow, Robert M. (February 1956). "A contribution to the theory of economic growth". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 70 (1): 65–94. doi:10.2307/1884513. hdl:10338.dmlcz/143862. JSTOR 1884513. Pdf.
  • Cass D (1965): "Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation, The Review of Economic Studies, 32(3):233-240, jstor.
  • Solow, Robert M. (1957). "Technical change and the aggregate production function". Review of Economics and Statistics. 39 (3): 312–320. doi:10.2307/1926047. JSTOR 1926047. Pdf.
  • Besomi, Daniele (2001). "Harrod's dynamics and the theory of growth: the story of a mistaken attribution". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 25 (1): 79–96. doi:10.1093/cje/25.1.79. JSTOR 23599721.
  • Harrod, R. F. (1939). "An Essay in Dynamic Theory". The Economic Journal. 49 (193): 14–33. doi:10.2307/2225181. JSTOR 2225181.
  • Baumol, William J. (1986). "Productivity Growth, Convergence, and Welfare: What the Long-Run Data Show". The American Economic Review. 76 (5): 1072–1085. JSTOR 1816469.
  • Mankiw, N. Gregory; Romer, David; Weil, David N. (May 1992). "A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 107 (2): 407–437. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.335.6159. doi:10.2307/2118477. JSTOR 2118477. S2CID 1369978.

nber.org

psu.edu

citeseerx.ist.psu.edu

rcin.org.pl

semanticscholar.org

api.semanticscholar.org

usf.edu

scholarcommons.usf.edu

worldcat.org

search.worldcat.org